Tuesday, December 22, 2015

HISTORY OF CAPITALISM: A SHORT COURSE


Alas, the delicious charade of the title (its allusion to the historically famous and supremely consequential History Of The VKPb: A Short Course) will be lost on practically anybody who reads these lines, so what? At least, I have amused myself and a few other fossils of my ebbing generation…

This entry may be rightfully classified as a reader-edificational piece. But there is definitely more to it than can be squeezed into that definition. It is also part of a triptych, to be read in conjunction with my other two already posted entries:

2. History Of Socialism: No Corpus Delecti? Posted on March 30th, 2012.

3. History Of Communism: The Life Of A Specter. Posted on March 31st, 2012.

***

History of capitalism virtually begins with the prehistoric times, as a history of private ownership. Whether such a broad brush is justified or not is a moot matter. After all, capitalism, both good and bad, is always in the eye of the beholder.

Private ownership of some means of production has existed since the invention of agriculture. However, in feudal society much of this property was considered inalienable, thus capital markets were not established. (The last sentence, from Wikipedia, is practically nonsensical, considering the general capitalistic attitude toward all private property. In fact, it used to be much easier for the monarch in feudal times to dispossess a vassal of any or all of his possessions than for one capitalist to dispossess another. But, in so far as property transfer is concerned, a liege could not pass his property to another, because it was not his to begin with, but effectively belonged to the sovereign who on the other hand would have no qualms whatsoever to have such property change hands five times a day, if he wished so.)

Some writers see medieval guilds as forerunners of modern capitalist concerns (especially through the use of apprentices as a kind of paid laborer); but economic activity was bound by customs and controls, which, along with the rule of the aristocracy that would expropriate wealth via arbitrary fines, taxes and enforced loans, meant that profits were hard to accumulate. By the 18th century, though, such barriers to profit were overcome, and capitalism became the leading economic system in much of the world. (Which only proves that modern Western economies imposing high taxes and tariffs are either not capitalist or that capitalism has a different meaning in reality than in its attempted definitions.)

In the period between the late 15th century and the late 18th century the institution of private property was brought into existence in the full legal meaning of the term. Notable contribution to the theory of property is found in the works of John Locke, who argued that the right to private property is one of natural rights. (In fact, Locke argued in his 1690 Treatises on Government that “the reason why men enter into society is the preservation of his property.” How different that society must have been from the Demosthenes ideal, as he unequivocally declares that “the property of the lazy and shiftless belongs to those who are willing to face labor and danger.” Demosthenes, First Philippic.)

The earliest stage of modern capitalism arising between the 16th and 18th centuries is known as merchant capitalism and mercantilism. (For more on mercantilism see my Ethics Of Commerce entry.)

Mercantilism declined in Britain in mid-eighteenth century when a new group of economists led by Adam Smith challenged the basic mercantilist doctrine that the amount of the world’s wealth remained constant and that the state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state. However in less developed economies, such as Prussia and Russia, mercantilism still continued to find favor. (I’ll need to examine this claim regarding Russian mercantilism in other sources and either write a substantial commentary or drop the subject altogether. As of now, there is nothing particularly interesting in this narrative, but I will keep it here just in case, until the question is resolved either way.)

The mid-eighteenth century gave rise to industrial capitalism, made possible by the accumulation of vast amounts of capital under the merchant phase of capitalism and its investment in machinery. It marked the development of the factory system of manufacturing, characterized by a complex division of labor between and within work process and the routinization of work tasks; and finally established the global domination of the capitalist mode of production.

The rise of industrial capitalism was also associated with the end of mercantilism. Mid- to late-nineteenth-century Britain is widely regarded as a classic case of laissez-faire capitalism supplanting mercantilism in the 1840s. Following Smith and Ricardo, Britain embraced liberalism, promoting competition and market economy.

So far, so good. Industrial capitalism, related to the Industrial Revolution as a chicken to an egg, must have been an all-right thing. The trouble with capitalism was not what they did with the machines, but what they did with the money. Noam Chomsky, although referring to a much later event, puts his finger on the right spot, when he finds the origin of today’s catastrophic degeneration of the international capitalist system in the murky waters of financial machinations getting out of the Bretton-Woods control. So, here we are, say welcome to the gravedigger of all capitalism, the wonderful Mr. Hyde, or, officially, finance capitalism.

Finance capitalism and monopoly capitalism. In the late 19th century, control and direction of large areas of industry came into the hands of financiers. This period is defined as “finance capitalism,” characterized by a subordination of production to accumulation of money profits in a financial system. Major features of capitalism in this period include the establishment of huge industrial cartels or monopolies; the ownership and management of industry by financiers divorced from production processes, and the development of a complex system of banking, an equity market, and corporate holdings of capital through stock ownership. Increasingly, large industries and land became the subject of profit and loss by financial speculators.

Late 19th and early 20th century capitalism is also described as an era of “monopoly capitalism,” marked by the shift from laissez-faire to capital concentration into large monopolistic or oligopolistic holdings by banks and financiers, and marked by the growth of large corporations and a division of labor, separating shareholders, owners, and managers.

By the last quarter of the 19th century, the emergence of large industrial trusts had provoked legislation in the United States to reduce the monopolistic tendencies of the period. The federal government was playing a gradually larger role in passing antitrust laws and regulation of industrial standards for key industries of special public concern. By the end of the 19th century, economic depressions and boom and bust business cycles had become a recurring problem. In particular the Long Depression of the 1870’s and 1880’s and the Great Depression of the 1930’s affected almost the entire capitalist world, and generated discussion about capitalism’s long-term survival prospects. During 1930’s Marxist commentators often raised the possibility of capitalism’s decline or demise, often in contrast to the ability of the Soviet Union to avoid suffering the effects of the global depression. (Aha! It was the bagman unchained who had caused the depressions, and forced the hand of the government, whose interference was to defeat the capitalist dream.)

Capitalism after the Great Depression. The economic recovery of world’ s leading capitalist economies in the wake of the Great Depression and World War Two, accompanied by rapid growth, eased the doomsday talk, as far as the future survival of capitalism was concerned. (Yes, and here is the catch:)

In the period following the global depression of the 1930’s, the state played an increasingly prominent role in the capitalist system throughout much of the world. In 1929, for example, total government expenditures in the United States, federal, state and local, amounted to less than one-tenth of GNP; from the 1970’s they amounted to around one-third. Similar increases were seen in all industrialized capitalist economies, some of which, such as in France, have reached even higher ratios of government expenditures to GNP than the United States. These economies have since been widely described as mixed economies.

In other words, capitalism as-such ceased to exist at that time, validating Chomsky’s assertion that there’s nothing remotely like capitalism in existence, that, to the extent there ever was, it had disappeared by the 1920s or ’30s.

Which in my book brings the history of capitalism to an end, and this short course with it.

No comments:

Post a Comment